The High Cost of Free Incentive Parking

July 13th, 2016 by ant6n

I have a confession to make: I think park’n’rides, or incentive parking as we call them in Montreal, are a bad idea.

Everybody seems to be asking for more and more incentive parking these days, and anyone questioning the driving component of our transit cocktail model may incur the anger of drivers and get painted as some sort of tofu-loving anti-car zealot. Well, I don’t like tofu, but I don’t like free park’n’rides either. Besides being bad for the city, they just don’t make economic sense.

Most people assume providing parking basically costs nothing for a transit agency. Plop a parking lot next to a train station, and you never have to think about it again. Just drive to the station and take the train.

Except, it turns out that parking is surprisingly expensive.

First, there is the one-time expense to buy the land and then to build the parking lot. Then, the parking lot requires a variety of operating expenses for things like maintenance (snow clearing, salting, cleaning, raod work…), security (lighting, cameras), and taxes, to name a few.

It’s not so easy to figure out what the exact cost is to provide free parking, broken down per user and per day. One good source is this 2016 study analyzing the total cost of providing parking, that is, land, construction and maintenance costs, in the US. The following graph shows the annualized costs for different types of parking spaces (note: land and construction costs are amortized over 20 years):

parking-chart

According to the study, surface parking lots typically costs around $1000 in the suburbs and $2000 in the city per year to provide. Those numbers were for 2007 and in US Dollars, so after adjusting for inflation (9 years, 15% total) and converting to CAD, that’s about 1500$-3000$ per year. Every year. For one single parking spot.

Another source, Calgary Transit estimated its 2011 parking costs to ~700$-1642$ per year (assuming 20 year amortization for a lot, and 40 year amortization for a parking structure).

Another survey of parking of American Transit agencies found the average operating cost for a total of 288,000 parking spots to be 1,100 USD per year, or about 1,425 CAD (see this spreadsheet). What’s interesting is that even though the transit agencies charge around 4.50$ per day on average for parking, on average they only recover 34% of the parking costs.

Now, consider that every commuter parking spot can pretty much be used by only one car every day. One person, who drives to the train in the morning and picks up the car after work in the evening. If we’re lucky, we may get up to 1.3 people per vehicle, which is the average occupancy rate of a car.

Moreover, in Montreal, the commuter rail parking lots of the AMT have an occupancy rate of 80%, but the unused 20% still has to be paid for.

Overall, your typical free parking costs around $7.20 to $14.40 per weekday to provide, subsidized by the transit agency or the city.

$ 1500 / 260 work days = $5.77 per day
 $ 5.77 / 0.80 occupancy = $7.21 per day
$ 3000 / 260 work days = $11.54
 $ 11.54 / 0.80 occupancy = $14.42

In terms of economic efficiency, this is quite a waste of money. Instead of having drivers go downtown and have them pay for their own parking, everybody has to pay for the drivers who park near a transit station, on top of having to subsidize the transit itself as well. If this is an ‘incentive’ that society provides to encourage transit use, we’re getting a pretty bad return on investment. Because the advantage of a few drivers being able to park near transit does not outweigh the money that we collectively spend to provide that parking.

If we look at cost per user, it is much more efficient to provide bicycle-parking in those same lots. It is possible to fit 15-20 bicycles in the space required for one parking spot in a parking lot. That’s because the lot is actually twice as big as the actual space required by a car: you need one car-area to put the car, and the equivalent of another car-area for the car to drive to the parking spot.

Park’n’Ride at Terminus Chevrier, only about half the space is used by the parking spots

Park’n’Ride at Terminus Chevrier, only about half the space is used by the parking spots

And walking to the station is even more economically efficient – it’s free.

Comparing with Feeder Buses

Of course it’s not realistic for everybody to just cycle to transit stations, and many don’t live within walking distance. So how else can we bring people to the trains?

The most popular alternative is to provide feeder buses, which collect passengers and bring them to the bus station. And despite requiring drivers and equipment, a feeder bus may actually be cheaper than parking!

Unfortunately, transit agencies don’t generally provide enough information that allows estimating how much it costs to provider feeder buses per person, so we can only infer from available numbers.

In 2014, Translink, Vancouver’s Transit Agency, published a report which contains a table of costs for operating transit per passenger-kilometer.

cost-comparison

The chart shows blended operating costs, which is the overall operating cost for bus, metro, and rail combined, for several Canadian cities. We see from the graph that operating cost is lower in Calgary and higher in Ottawa and Edmonton. The difference is consistent with the transit model in every city: Calgary has an efficient light rail system, which is cheaper to operate than buses, because the vehicles are much larger, and most of their buses feed into the light rail. On the other hand, Edmonton and Ottawa have much smaller rail systems, and have to rely on the more expensive-to-operate buses.

According to this chart, Montreal’s transit operating cost was a little over $0.30 per passenger kilometre in 2013. Since this number does not take into account capital costs, we can adjust it up by about 20% (capital costs for buses is about 20% of operating costs) and round it up to $0.40 to account for the blending of different modes.

This means that bringing a person to a train station 2km away by bus costs about $1.60 per day (2 trips). Even if the person lives 6km away, this would only cost $4.80, which is still much less than providing parking, which costs $7 or more!

Note on distance: on the island of Montreal, only few people are farther than 6km away from a rail station, Commuter rail included (which is where most of the parking is). Even in the South Shore (Brossard and Longueuil), most are within 4km of the major transit terminals (Terminus Longueuil, Terminus Panama, Terminus Chevrier) and the commuter rail stations.

Overall we get the following cost estimates:

transit-access-chart

Alternative Use of the Space used for Parking

If you get more people to take buses from their homes, walk, or maybe even take a bicycle, you free up the land right next to the station. So instead of wasting valuable transit-adjacent land on parking the land can now be developed, to build apartment, commercial or office buildings and generate property taxes for the city, which in turn can be used to improve feeder buses. (The cities already pay most of the subsidies to operate transit).

People will want to live there, because they can quickly get downtown and businesses would want to locate there, because many people pass through the area. Transit stations would become the centers of little transit towns.

But also, you suddenly have people who don’t need to rely on either parking or feeder buses to get to the transit station – because they’re already right next to the station. Anybody who doesn’t need a bus or a parking spot to get to transit will be less expensive for the transit system as a whole.

Transit systems are based on cross-subsidies: some people pay more, so that others pay less. Short trip commuters subsidize those who go from one end of the line to the other. Metro users subsidize bus-&-metro users. The person who takes one ride pays the same as the person who uses a transfer.

And free incentive parking users should realize that they are benefitting from a premium service provided below cost – and provided to those who are more likely to be better off. In effect, those walking, cycling and even those taking buses are subsidizing the car owners who receive free parking.

When people complain about the lack incentive parking, remember that free parking is uneconomical. Money was invested in parking, when it could have been invested in service.

Space was allocated to parking, when it could have been developed to bring in tax revenue.

And maybe we should realize that parking at rail stations should not be free.


Appendix: What does a Developed Train Station look like?

The following shows the comparison of two suburban transit stations, inside suburban towns of similar sizes that are in turn in metropolitan areas of similar size. One stop is immediately surrounded by parking, the other by a walkable town.

Above: Sainte-Therese (population 26K), 25km from downtown Montreal (pop 3.9M). 
Below: Königs-Wusterhausen (pop 34K), 28km from downtown Berlin (pop 4.3M).

st-therese-vs-konigs-wusterhausen-labels

In Sainte-Therese, the rail station is close to the middle of town. But the parking is plenty and right next to the station, displacing the chance for a town centre. There are some condo-buildings around, but most of the area surrounding the station consists of low-density commercial buildings, most with more parking. There’s also a large bus terminus with 11 bays using up a lot of space as well. The terminus services thirteen lines.

By comparison, the Train Station in Königs-Wusterhausen is the center of a small town, with a pedestrian plaza, a mixed-use town-centre, plenty of bicycle parking, and bus stops served by a total of fifteen bus lines. Parking is still provided, because of increasing motorization levels, sprawl, and the resulting pressure to provide parking, but it’s pushed further away from the station, mostly to the far right.

konigs-wusterhausen-bus-station
The primary bus stop in Königs-Wusterhausen is small in area, because its primary purpose is to pick up and drop off passengers, not to store buses in the middle of a town. Image source.

10 Responses to “The High Cost of Free Incentive Parking”

  1. David Tighe Says:

    I remember when the buzz-word was kiss-and-ride; park-and ride was less important since one-car families were common. Kissing is still in fashion but the idea of your wife having to get up to drive you to the station would seem absurd or even sexist today. Anyway, she had probably already left for work.

    You raise an interesting point but remember that the social benefit from preventing that car polluting and congesting all the way downtown and then filling valuable space all day is significant. Nevertheless, free or small parking charges for the driver are inequitable. I have noticed that in the UK, for example, parking costs even at distant commuter stations are quite high and have already wondered at the logic of having them free here especially when they are already full by dawn.

  2. ant6n Says:

    @David
    If we invested the money we saved on parking, plus the money we gain from developing stations into transit service, then the incentives become more useful, and more equitable:

    a) drive all the way downtown and pay 15$/day for parking
    b) take a feeder bus or cycle to the station and pay 4$/day for transit.

    Sure it cannot capture everybody, but it can move a hell of a lot more people than for example the 300 parking spaces at station Anjou of the Mascouche line.

  3. ant6n Says:

    I guess part of the issue is that if the alternative is that drivers feel compelled to drive downtown and park there, then the market will ensure that’s not possible. We surely won’t provide anymore parking downtown, so if everybody wants to drive there the costs would become prohibitive. Right now the public expensively subsidizes that some percentage of drivers don’t go downtwn, which effectively reduces parking pressure downtown and keeps the prices lower.

    The point is, the parking supply downtown is the limiting factor in any case, always. So changing the parking-equation by providing suburban parking is moot.

  4. David Tighe Says:

    Given that the objective is to take cars off the roads, especially those going downtown at peak periods, in Utopia we would implement a parking or congestion pricing policy in the downtown area that makes motorists pay the real costs, we would add a minimum of 0,25$/ lit to gas prices, and we would set parking tariffs at stations at the price that will just fill them.
    Montreal is not Utopia so let us just improvise and maximize our vote.
    Sorry for the cynicism: it is not really very productive

  5. ant6n Says:

    I don’t think that getting cars of the road is actually the objective of transit.

    The objective is moving people.

    Right now we’re in a situation where basically any decent transit we provide will be filled up. So we should strive towards mobility, i.e. moving as many people as possible. So that means providing as much service as possible, to those who can’t afford cars and to those who don’t want to drive. We shouldn’t divert money for those goals to trying to bribe drivers into not driving by giving them a premium service below cost.

    Or, to express it more postively: right now in the West Island people keep asking for more parking on the Deux-Montagnes line. If instead we increased the service to rapid transit levels and provided good feeder buses, a lot of people would take it. Even people who drive today would start taking all-transit trips.

  6. David Tighe Says:

    I agree.However, at present, the implicit strategy seems to be to continue to maximize mobility by keeping people dependent on cars. Unfortunately they continue to be the cheapest and fastest way of getting around. The constraints on this strategy must be recognized, such as pollution, CO2 levels, congestion reducing mobility for all, exclusion of those who do not or cannot use a car etc and then woven into an explicit strategy of appropriate pricing, competitive options to cars, from bicycles to public transport, and so on.

    I do realise that this diatribe is not exactly fresh and innovative and it is completely off the point but the basic problem remains that there is no political will to even define much less implement such a strategy because of the perceived political costs involved. There are isolated efforts to tinker with this glaring fact: new metro cars, a display to tell you when the next bus is coming, a cosmetic bus lane, even REM which although I rather admire it, is terribly badly integrated, but they are merely a few crumbs of a strategy. Maybe this is all a democracy can come up with?

  7. emdx Says:

    The main problem is the NIMBYes who will froth ballistically at the mere mention of increasing density in their suburbs.

    This is why the city needs to be re-merged, without boroughs and where planning is centrally done so suburbanites can no longer stand in the way of progress.

    IIRC, the Caisse plan for their transit network precisely calls for densifying around stations, and taking a cut of the tax revenue. Basically, that’s a return to the streetcar suburbs of 100-130 years ago…

  8. ant6n Says:

    @emdx
    The REM calls for TOD, but then they built every new station along a highway. So I doubt it’s going to work. To me it looks mostly like a desire to make money building mega-developments, instead of building livable, walkable places.

    I think it would be better if they had a more urban routing in the West Island (e.g. Salaberry), and have more frequent stops that are actually _on_ the perpendicular arteries. Corridors like St-Jean are already slowly densifying, and transit stops would make it even easier. If you build the transit but make nearby space available for development, it will happen eventually.

    Suburbanites have to understand that more density and transit along their corridors will increase their quality of life, it will bring services within walking distance and increase everybody’s health. It won’t destroy their way of life, people can still have their single family houses if they want.

  9. Matthew Says:

    Here in Cambridge, UK we have a debate about park-and-ride charges. However these park-and-rides are for bus services into the centre, not train services.

    The city introduced a £1 per-car charge last year on the park-and-ride car parks. Then each adult has to pay £2.70 for a return ticket on the bus.

    The city centre has several multi-storey car parks available. Prices vary, but let’s say that they are between £2-3 per hour for a typical shopping trip of under 4 hours, and on the order of £25 for a full working day.

    There are many streets in the city with unrestricted parking so that anyone may come and use them, albeit most of these streets are outside of the centre and may not be familiar to occasional visitors.

    So what happens: during the week, all of the unrestricted streets are cluttered with commuter parking during the day. We know this because the streets all become empty of parked cars after 5 pm! The buses get caught in massive car congestion and are terribly unreliable.

    And on the weekends, when shoppers come to town, there is a queue a mile long to get into the multi-storey car parks, backing up all the way out of town. Blocking the park-and-ride buses, in fact!

    So your typical shopping family probably looks at the options and says “I could pay £6.40 (or more) to use a park-n-ride and still get stuck in traffic, or I can pay £2-3 per hour to get stuck in traffic but inside my own vehicle, or I could try and find an unrestricted parking space.”

    There’s extreme political resistance to raising the city centre multi-storey parking charges. And while putting parking restrictions on the streets seems to be popular, we’re still waiting for the process to go through (maybe next year, if we’re lucky).

    Many of us think that the park-and-ride charges should be dropped and the bus fares lowered. What do you think?

  10. Jérémie Dunn Says:

    The problem is that the rails are often built before the city/borough where it is, before the streets that allow us to get to these rails and before the implantation of the stations. It is the exact opposite of the TOD philosophy. This gives us poorly located stations, poorly accessible from major streets and then poorly accessible by bus because it means line created for the only purpose of drivant people to the train stations. In that situation, the car is the only efficient say to catch a train.

    Many train stations are not located on an idéal spot but on least bad location for X city of borough.

Leave a Reply